
In the previous chapter, we studied concepts related to a firm’s production function and cost curves. The focus of this chapter is different. Here we ask : how does a firm decide how much to produce? Our answer to this question is by no means simple or uncontroversial. We base our answer on a critical, if somewhat unreasonable, assumption about firm behaviour – a firm, we maintain, is a ruthless profit maximiser. So, the amount that a firm produces and sells in the market is that which maximises its profit. The structure of this chapter is as follows. We first set up and examine in detail the profit maximisation problem of a firm. This done, we derive a firm’s supply curve. The supply curve shows the levels of output that a firm chooses to produce for different values of the market price. Finally, we study how to aggregate the supply curves of individual firms and obtain the market supply curve. 4.1 PERFECT COMPETITION: DEFINING FEATURES In order to analyse a firm’s profit maximisation problem, we must first specify the market environment in which the firm functions. In this chapter, we study a market environment called perfect competition. A perfectly competitive market has two defining features 1. The market consists of buyers and sellers (that is, firms). All firms in the market produce a certain homogeneous (that is, undifferentiated) good. 2. Each buyer and seller in the market is a price-taker. Since the first feature of a perfectly competitive market is easy to understand, we focus on the second feature. From the viewpoint of a firm, what does price-taking entail? A price-taking firm believes that should it set a price above the market price, it will be unable to sell any quantity of the good that it produces. On the other hand, should the set price be less than or equal to the market price, the firm can sell as many units of the good as it wants to sell. From the viewpoint of a buyer, what does price-taking entail? A buyer would obviously like to buy the good at the lowest possible price. However, a price-taking buyer believes that should she ask for a price below the market price, no firm will be willing to sell to her. On the other hand, should the price asked be greater than or equal to the market price, the buyer can obtain as many units of the good as she desires to buy. Since this chapter deals exclusively with firms, we probe no further into buyer behaviour. Instead, we identify conditions under which price-taking is a reasonable assumption for firms. Price-taking is often thought to be a reasonable assumption when the market has many firms and buyers have perfect information about the price prevailing in the market. Why? Let us start with a situation wherein each firm in the market charges the same (market) price and sells some amount of the good. Suppose, now, that a certain firm raises its price above the market price. Observe that since all firms produce the same good and all buyers are aware of the market price, the firm in question loses all its buyers. Furthermore, as these buyers switch their purchases to other firms, no “adjustment” problems arise; their demands are readily accommodated when there are many firms in the market. Recall, now, that an individual firm’s inability to sell any amount of the good at a price exceeding the market price is precisely what the price-taking assumption stipulates. We have indicated that in a perfectly competitive market, a firm believes that it can sell as many units of the good as it wants by setting a price less than or equal to the market price. But, if this is the case, surely there is no reason to set a price lower than the market price. In other words, should the firm desire to sell some amount of the good, the price that it sets is exactly equal to the market price. A firm earns revenue by selling the good that it produces in the market. Let the market price of a unit of the good be p. Let q be the quantity of the good produced, and therefore sold, by the firm at price p. Then, total revenue (TR) of the firm is defined as the market price of the good (p) multiplied by the firm’s output (q). Hence, TR = p × q To make matters concrete, consider the following numerical example. Let the market for candles be perfectly competitive and let the market price of a box of candles be Rs 10. For a candle manufacturer, Table 4.1 shows how total revenue is related to output. Notice that when no box is produced, TR is equal to zero; if one box of candles is produced, TR is equal to 1 × Rs 10 = Rs 10; if two boxes of candles are produced, TR is equal to 2 × Rs 10 = Rs 20; and so on. With the example done, let us return to a more general setting. In a perfectly competitive market, a firm views the market price, p, as given. With the market price fixed at p, the total revenue curve of a firm shows the relationship between its total revenue (y-axis) and its output (x-axis). Figure 4.1 shows the total revenue curve of a firm. Three observations are relevant here. First, when the output is zero, the total revenue of the firm is also zero. Therefore, the TR curve passes through point O. Second, the total revenue increases as the output goes up. Moreover, the equation ‘TR = p × q’ is that of a Table 4.1: Total Revenue Boxes sold TR (in Rs) 0 0 1 10 2 20 3 30 4 40 5 50 straight line. This means that the TR curve is an upward rising straight line. Third, consider the slope of this straight line. When the output is one unit (horizontal distance Oq1 in Figure 4.1), the total revenue (vertical height Aq1 in Figure 4.1) is p × 1 = p. Therefore, the slope of the straight line is Aq1/Oq1 = p. Now consider Figure 4.2. Here, we plot the market price (y-axis) for different values of a firm’s output (x-axis). Since the Total Revenue curve. The total revenue curve of market price is fixed at p, we a firm shows the relationship between the total obtain a horizontal straight line revenue that the firm earns and the output level of that cuts the y-axis at a height the firm. The slope of the curve, Aq1/Oq1, is the equal to p. This horizontal market price. straight line is called the price line. The price line also depicts the demand curve facing a firm. Observe that Figure 4.2 shows that the market price, p, is independent of a firm’s output. This means that a firm can sell as many units of the good as it wants to sell at price p. The average revenue ( AR ) of a firm is defined as total revenue per unit of output. 54 Recall that if a firm’s output is q and the market price is p, then TR equals p × q. Hence Introductory Microeconomics TR p ×q AR = = = p Price Line. The price line shows the relationship qq between the market price and a firm’s output level. The vertical height of the price line is equal to the In other words, for a price-taking market price, p. firm, average revenue equals the market price. The marginal revenue (MR) of a firm is defined as the increase in total revenue for a unit increase in the firm’s output. Consider a situation where the firm’s output is increased from q0 to (q0 + 1). Given market price p, notice that MR = (TR from output (q0 + 1)) – (TR from output q0) = (p × (q0 + 1)) – (pq0) = p In other words, for a price-taking firm, marginal revenue equals the market price. Setting the algebra aside, the intuition for this result is quite simple. When a firm increases its output by one unit, this extra unit is sold at the market price. Hence, the firm’s increase in total revenue from the one-unit output expansion – that is, MR – is precisely the market price. A firm produces and sells a certain amount of a good. The firm’s profit, denoted by π, is defined to be the difference between its total revenue (TR) and its total cost of production (TC ).1 In other words π = TR – TC Clearly, the gap between TR and TC is the firm’s earnings net of costs. A firm wishes to maximise its profit. The critical question is: at what output level is the firm’s profit maximised? Assuming that the firm’s output is perfectly divisible, we now show that if there is a positive output level, q0, at which profit is maximised, then three conditions must hold: 1. The market price, p, is equal to the marginal cost at q0. 2. The marginal cost is non-decreasing at q0. 3. In the short run, the market price, p, must be greater than or equal to the average variable cost at q0. In the long run, the market price, p, must be greater than or equal to the average cost at q0. 4.3.1 Condition 1 Consider condition 1. We show that condition 1 is true by arguing that a profitmaximising firm will not produce at an output level where market price exceeds marginal cost or marginal cost exceeds market price. We check both the cases. Case 1: Price greater than MC is ruled out Consider Figure 4.3 and note that at the output level q2, the market price, p, exceeds the marginal cost. We claim that q2 cannot be a profit-maximising output level. Why? Observe that for all output levels slightly to the right of q2, the market price continues to exceed the marginal cost. So, pick an output level q3 slightly to the right of q2 such that the market price exceeds the marginal cost for all output levels between q2 and q3. Suppose, now, that the firm increases its output level from q2 to q3. The increase in the total revenue of the firm from this output expansion is just the market price multiplied by the change in quantity; that is, the area of the rectangle q2q3CB. On the other hand, the increase in total cost associated with this output expansion is just the area under the marginal cost curve between output levels q2 and q3; that is, the area of the region q2q3XW. But, a comparison of the two areas shows that the firm’s profit is higher when its output level is q3 rather than q2. But, if this is the case, q2 cannot be a profitmaximising output level. Case 2: Price less than MC is ruled out Consider Figure 4.3 and note that at the output level q5, the market price, p, is less than the marginal cost. We claim that q5 cannot be a profit-maximising output level. Why? Observe that for all output levels slightly to the left of q5, the market price remains lower than the marginal cost. So, pick an output level q4 slightly to the left of q5 such that the market price is less than the marginal cost for all output levels between q4 and q5. Suppose, now, that the firm cuts its output level from q5 to q4. The decrease in the total revenue of the firm from this output contraction is just the market 1It is a convention in economics to denote profit with the Greek letter π. 55 price multiplied by the change in quantity; that is, the area of the rectangle q4q5EF. On the other hand, the decrease in total cost brought about by this output contraction is the area under the marginal cost curve between output levels q and q; that is, the area of the region qqZY. But, a comparison of the 45 4 5 two areas shows that the firm’s profit is higher when its output level is q4 rather than q5. But, if this is the case, q5 cannot be a profit-maximising output level. 4.3.2 Condition 2 Consider the second condition that must hold when the profitmaximising output level is positive. Why is it the case that the marginal cost curve cannot slope downwards at the profitmaximising output level? To answer this question, refer once again to Figure 4.3. Note that at the output level q1, the market price is equal to the marginal cost; however, the marginal cost curve is downward sloping. We claim Conditions 1 and 2 for profit maximisation. that q cannot be a profit 1 The figure is used to demonstrate that when the maximising output level. Why? market price is p, the output level of a profit-Observe that for all output maximising firm cannot be q1 (marginal cost levels slightly to the left of q, curve, MC, is downward sloping), q2 (market 1 price exceeds marginal cost), or q5 (marginal cost the market price is lower than exceeds market price). the marginal cost. But, the argument outlined in case 2 of section 3.1 immediately implies that the firm’s profit at an output level slightly smaller than q1 exceeds that corresponding to the output level q. This being the 56 1 case, q1 cannot be a profitmaximising output level. 4.3.3 Condition 3 Consider the third condition that must hold when the profitmaximising output level is positive. Notice that the third condition has two parts: one part applies in the short run while the other applies in the long run. Case 1: Price must be greater than or equal to AVC in the short run Price-AVC Relationship with Profit We will show that the statement of Maximisation (Short Run). The figure is used to demonstrate that a profit-maximising firm Case 1 (see above) is true by produces zero output in the short run when the arguing that a profit-maximising market price, p, is less than the minimum of its firm, in the short run, will not average variable cost (AVC). If the firm’s output produce at an output level wherein level is q1, the firm’s total variable cost exceeds the market price is lower than its revenue by an amount equal to the area of the AVC. rectangle pEBA. Let us turn to Figure 4.4. Observe that at the output level q1, the market price p is lower than the AVC. We claim that q1 cannot be a profit-maximising output level. Why? Notice that the firm’s total revenue at q1 is as follows TR = Price × Quantity = Vertical height Op × width Oq1 = The area of rectangle OpAq1 Similarly, the firm’s total variable cost at q1 is as follows TVC = Average variable cost × Quantity = Vertical height OE × Width Oq1 = The area of rectangle OEBq1 Now recall that the firm’s profit at q1 is TR – (TVC + TFC); that is, [the area of rectangle OpAq1] – [the area of rectangle OEBq1] – TFC. What happens if the firm produces zero output? Since output is zero, TR and TVC are zero as well. Hence, the firm’s profit at zero output is equal to – TFC. But, the area of rectangle OpAq1 is strictly less than the area of rectangle OEBq1. Hence, the firm’s profit at q1 is strictly less than what it obtains by not producing at all. This means, of course, that q1 cannot be a profit-maximising output level. Case 2: Price must be greater than or equal to AC in the long run We will show that the statement of Case 2 (see above) is true by arguing that a profit-maximising firm, in the long run, will not produce at an output level wherein the market price is lower than the AC. Let us turn to Figure 4.5. Observe that at the output level q1, the market price p is lower than the (long run) AC. We claim that q cannot be a profit-maximising 157 output level. Why? Notice that the firm’s total revenue, TR, at q1 is the area of the rectangle OpAq1 (the product of price and quantity) while the firm’s total cost, TC , is the area of the rectangle OEBq1 (the product of average cost and quantity). Since the area of rectangle OEBq1 is larger than the area of rectangle OpAq, the firm Price-AC Relationship with Profit 1 Maximisation (Long Run). The figure is used incurs a loss at the output level to demonstrate that a profit-maximising firm q. But, in the long run set-up, a 1produces zero output in the long run when the firm that shuts down production market price, p, is less than the minimum of itshas a profit of zero. This means, long run average cost (LRAC). If the firm’s output of course, that q is not a profit-level is q, the firm’s total cost exceeds its revenue 11 maximising output level. by an amount equal to the area of rectangle pEBA. 4.3.4 The Profit Maximisation Problem: Graphical Representation Using the material in sections 3.1, 3.2 and 3.3, let us graphically represent a firm’s profit maximisation problem in the short run. Consider Figure 4.6. Notice that the market price is p. Equating the market price with the (short run) marginal cost, we obtain the output level q0. At q0, observe that SMC slopes upwards and p exceeds AVC. Since the three conditions discussed in sections 3.1-3.3 are satisfied at q0, we maintain that the profitmaximising output level of the firm is q0. What happens at q0? The total revenue of the firm at q0 is the area of rectangle OpAq0 (the product of price and quantity) while the total cost at q0 is the area of rectangle OEBq0 (the Geometric Representation of Profit product of short run average cost Maximisation (Short Run). Given market and quantity). So, at q0, the firm price p, the output level of a profit-maximising earns a profit equal to the area of firm is q0. At q0, the firm’s profit is equal to the rectangle EpAB. the area of rectangle EpAB. 4.4 SUPPLY CURVE OF A FIRM The supply curve of a firm shows the levels of output (plotted on the x-axis) that the firm chooses to produce corresponding to different values of the market price (plotted on the y-axis). Of course, for a given market price, the output level of a profit-maximising firm will depend on whether we are considering the short run or the long run. Accordingly, we distinguish between the short run supply curve and the long run supply curve. 4.4.1 Short Run Supply Curve of a Firm 58 Let us turn to Figure 4.7 and derive a firm’s short run supply curve. We shall split this derivation into two parts. We first determine a firm’s profitmaximising output level when the market price is greater than or equal to the minimum AVC. This done, we determine the firm’s profit-maximising output level when the market price is less than the minimum AVC. Case 1: Price is greater than or equal to the minimum AVC Suppose the market price is p, Market Price Values. The figure shows the 1output levels chosen by a profit-maximising firm which exceeds the minimum AVC. in the short run for two values of the market price: We start out by equating p with 1p1 and p2. When the market price is p1, the output SMC on the rising part of the SMC level of the firm is q1; when the market price iscurve; this leads to the output level p2, the firm produces zero output. q1. Note also that the AVC at q1 does not exceed the market price, p1. Thus, all three conditions highlighted in section 3 are satisfied at q1. Hence, when the market price is p1, the firm’s output level in the short run is equal to q1. Case 2: Price is less than the minimum AVC Suppose the market price is p2, which is less than the minimum AVC. We have argued (see condition 3 in section 3) that if a profit-maximising firm produces a positive output in the short run, then the market price, p2, must be greater than or equal to the AVC at that output level. But notice from Figure 4.7 that for all positive output levels, AVC strictly exceeds p2. In other words, it cannot be the case that the firm supplies a positive output. So, if the market price is p2, the firm produces zero output. Combining cases 1 and 2, we reach an important conclusion. A firm’s short run supply curve is the rising part of the SMC curve from and above the minimum AVC together with zero output for all prices strictly less than the The Short Run Supply Curve of a Firm. The minimum AVC. In figure 4.8, the short run supply curve of a firm, which is based on its short run marginal cost curve (SMC) and bold line represents the short run average variable cost curve (AVC), is represented supply curve of the firm. by the bold line. 4.4.2 Long Run Supply Curve of a Firm Let us turn to Figure 4.9 and derive the firm’s long run supply curve. As in the short run case, we split the derivation into two parts. We first determine the 59 firm’s profit-maximising output level when the market price is greater than or equal to the minimum (long run) AC. This done, we determine the firm’s profit-maximising output level when the market price is less than the minimum (long run) AC. Case 1: Price greater than or equal to the minimum LRAC Suppose the market price is p1, which exceeds the minimum LRAC. Upon equating p1 with LRMC on the rising part of the Profit maximisation in the Long Run for LRMC curve, we obtain output Different Market Price Values. The figure level q1. Note also that the LRAC shows the output levels chosen by a profit maximising firm in the long run for two values at q1 does not exceed the market of the market price: p1 and p2. When the market price, p1. Thus, all three price is p1, the output level of the firm is q1; conditions highlighted in when the market price is p2, the firm produces section 3 are satisfied at q1. zero output. Hence, when the market price is p1, the firm’s supplies in the long run become an output equal to q1. Case 2: Price less than the minimum LRAC Suppose the market price is p2, which is less than the minimum LRAC. We have argued (see condition 3 in section 3) that if a profit-maximising firm produces a positive output in the long run, the market price, p2, must be greater than or equal to the LRAC at that output level. But notice from Figure 4.9 that for all positive output levels, LRAC strictly exceeds p2. In other words, it cannot be the case that the firm supplies a positive output. So, when the market price is p2, the firm produces zero output. Combining cases 1 and 2, we reach an important conclusion. A firm’s long run supply curve is the rising part of the LRMC curve from and above the minimum LRAC together with zero output for all The Long Run Supply Curve of a Firm. The long run supply curve of a firm, which is based on prices less than the minimum its long run marginal cost curve (LRMC) and long LRAC. In Figure 4.10, the bold line run average cost curve (LRAC), is represented by represents the long run supply the bold line. curve of the firm. 4.4.3 The Shut Down Point Previously, while deriving the supply curve, we have discussed that in the short run the firm continues to produce as long as the price remains greater than or 60 equal to the minimum of AVC. Therefore, along the supply curve as we move down, the last price-output combination at which the firm produces positive output is the point of minimum AVC where the SMC curve cuts the AVC curve. Below this, there will be no production. This point is called the short run shut down point of the firm. In the long run, however, the shut down point is the minimum of LRAC curve. 4.4.4 The Normal Profit and Break-even Point A firm uses different kinds of inputs in the production process. To acquire some of them, the firm has to pay directly. For example, if a firm employs labour it has to pay wages to them; if it uses some raw materials, it has to buy them. There may be some other kinds of inputs which the firm owns, and therefore, does not need to pay to anybody for them. These inputs though do not involve any explicit cost, they involve some opportunity cost to the firm. The firm instead of using these inputs in the current production process could have used them for some other purpose and get some return. This forgone return is the opportunity cost to the firm. The firm normally expects to earn a profit that along with the explicit costs can also cover the opportunity costs. The profit level that is just enough to cover the explicit costs and opportunity costs of the firm is called the normal profit. If a firm includes both its explicit costs and opportunity costs in the calculation of total cost, the normal profit becomes that level of profit when total revenue equals total cost, i.e., the zero level of profit. Profit that a firm earns over and above the normal profit is called the super-normal profit. In the long run, a firm does not produce if it earns anything less than the normal profit. In the short run, however, it may produce even if the profit is less than this level. The point on the supply curve at which a firm earns normal profit is called the break-even point of the firm. The point of minimum average cost at which the supply curve cuts the LRAC curve (in short run, SAC curve) is therefore the break-even point of a firm. In the previous section, we have seen that a firm’s supply curve is a part of its marginal cost curve. Thus, any factor that affects a firm’s marginal cost curve is of course a determinant of its supply curve. In this section, we discuss three such factors. 4.5.1 Technological Progress Suppose a firm uses two factors of production – say, capital and labour – to produce a certain good. Subsequent to an organisational innovation by the firm, the same levels of capital and labour now produce more units of output. Put differently, to produce a given level of output, the organisational innovation allows the firm to use fewer units of inputs. It is expected that this will lower the firm’s marginal cost at any level of output; that is, there is a rightward (or downward) shift of the MC curve. As the firm’s supply curve is essentially a segment of the MC curve, technological progress shifts the supply curve of the firm to the right. At any given market price, the firm now supplies more units of output. 4.5.2 Input Prices A change in input prices also affects a firm’s supply curve. If the price of an input (say, the wage rate of labour) increases, the cost of production rises. The consequent increase in the firm’s average cost at any level of output is usually accompanied by an increase in the firm’s marginal cost at any level of output; that is, there is a leftward (or upward) shift of the MC curve. This means that the firm’s supply curve shifts to the left: at any given market price, the firm now supplies fewer units of output. 61 4.5.3 Unit Tax A unit tax is a tax that the government imposes per unit sale of output. For example, suppose that the unit tax imposed by the government is Rs 2. Then, if the firm produces and sells 10 units of the good, the total tax that the firm must pay to the government is 10 × Rs 2 = Rs 20. How does the long run supply curve of a firm change when a unit tax is imposed? Let us turn to figure 4.11. Before the unit tax is imposed, LRMC0 and LRAC0 are, respectively, the long run Cost Curves and the Unit Tax. LRAC0 and marginal cost curve and the long LRMC0 are, respectively, the long run average cost run average cost curve of the firm. curve and the long run marginal cost curve of a firm before a unit tax is imposed. LRAC1 and LRMC1 Now, suppose the government are, respectively, the long run average cost curve puts in place a unit tax of Rs t. and the long run marginal cost curve of a firm Since the firm must pay an extra after a unit tax of Rs t is imposed. Rs t for each unit of the good produced, the firm’s long run average cost and long run marginal cost at any level of output increases by Rs t. In Figure 4.11, LRMC1 and LRAC1 are, respectively, the long run marginal cost curve and the long run average cost curve of the firm upon imposition of the unit tax. Recall that the long run supply curve of a firm is the rising part of the LRMC curve 62 from and above the minimum LRAC together with zero output for all prices less than the minimum LRAC. Using this observation in Figure 4.12, it is immediate that S0 and S1 are, respectively, the long run supply curve of the firm before and after the imposition of the unit tax. Notice that the unit tax shifts the firm’s long run supply Supply Curves and Unit Tax. S0 is the supply curve to the left: at any given curve of a firm before a unit tax is imposed. After market price, the firm now a unit tax of Rs t is imposed, S1 represents the supplies fewer units of output. supply curve of the firm. 4.6 MARKET SUPPLY CURVE The market supply curve shows the output levels (plotted on the x-axis) that firms in the market produce in aggregate corresponding to different values of the market price (plotted on the y-axis). How is the market supply curve derived? Consider a market with n firms: firm 1, firm 2, firm 3, and so on. Suppose the market price is fixed at p. Then, the output produced by the n firms in aggregate is [supply of firm 1 at price p] + [supply of firm 2 at price p] + ... + [supply of firm n at price p]. In other words, the market supply at price p is the summation of the supplies of individual firms at that price. Let us now construct the market supply curve geometrically with just two firms in the market: firm 1 and firm 2. The two firms have different cost structures. Firm 1 will not produce anything if the market price is less than p1 while firm 2 will not produce anything if the market price is less than p2 . Assume also that p2 is greater than p1. In panel (a) of Figure 4.13 we have the supply curve of firm 1, denoted by S1; in panel (b), we have the supply curve of firm 2, denoted by S2. Panel (c) of Figure 4.13 shows the market supply curve, denoted by Sm. When the market price is strictly below p1 , both firms choose not to produce any amount of the good; hence, market supply will also be zero for all such prices. For a market price greater than or equal to p1 but strictly less than p2 , only firm 1 will produce a positive amount of the good. Therefore, in this range, the market supply curve coincides with the supply curve of firm 1. For a market price greater than or equal to p2 , both firms will have positive output levels. For example, consider a situation wherein the market price assumes the value p3 (observe that p3 exceeds p2 ). Given p3, firm 1 supplies q3 units of output while firm 2 supplies q4 units of output. So, the market supply at price p is q, where q = q + q. Notice 35534 how the market supply curve, Sm, in panel (c) is being constructed: we obtain Sm by taking a horizontal summation of the supply curves of the two firms in the market, S1 and S2. It should be noted that the market supply curve has been derived for a fixed number of firms in the market. As the number of firms changes, the market supply curve shifts as well. Specifically, if the number of firms in the market increases (decreases), the market supply curve shifts to the right (left). We now supplement the graphical analysis given above with a related numerical example. Consider a market with two firms: firm 1 and firm 2. Let the 63 supply curve of firm 1 be as follows ⎧0: p < 10 S(p) = ⎨ 1⎩p –10 : p ≥ 10 The Market Supply Curve Panel. (a) shows the supply curve of firm 1. Panel (b) shows the supply curve of firm 2. Panel (c) shows the market supply curve, which is obtained by taking a horizontal summation of the supply curves of the two firms. Notice that S1(p) indicates that (1) firm 1 produces an output of 0 if the market price, p, is strictly less than 10, and (2) firm 1 produces an output of (p – 10) if the market price, p, is greater than or equal to 10. Let the supply curve of firm 2 be as follows ⎧0: p < 15 S(p) = ⎨ 2⎩p –15 : p ≥ 15 The interpretation of S2(p) is identical to that of S1(p), and is, hence, omitted. Now, the market supply curve, Sm(p), simply sums up the supply curves of the two firms; in other words Sm(p) = S1(p) + S2(p) But, this means that Sm(p) is as follows ⎧0: p < 10 ⎪ Sm(p) = ⎨p –10 : p ≥ 10 and p < 15 ⎪ ⎩(p – 10) + (p – 15) = 2p –25 : p ≥ 15 Introductory Microeconomics The price elasticity of supply of a good measures the responsiveness of quantity supplied to changes in the price of the good. More specifically, the price elasticity of supply, denoted by eS, is defined as follows Percentage change in quantity supplied Price elasticity of supply (eS) = Percentage change in price Given the market supply curve of a good (that is, Sm(p)), let q0 be the quantity of the good supplied to the market when its market price is p0. For some reason, the market price of the good changes from p0 to p1. Let q1 be the quantity of the good supplied to the market when the market price is p1. Notice that 64 when the market price moves from p0 to p1, the percentage change in price is 100 × (p1– p0) ; similarly, when the quantity supplied moves from q0 to q1, 0 p (q1– q0) the percentage change in quantity supplied is 100 × . So 0 q 100 10 100 × (q – q )/ qq /q –1 e= = S 100 10 100 × (p – p )/ pp / p –1 To make matters concrete, consider the following numerical example. Suppose the market for cricket balls is perfectly competitive. When the price of a cricket ball is Rs10, let us assume that 200 cricket balls are produced in aggregate by the firms in the market. When the price of a cricket ball rises to Rs 30, let us assume that 1,000 cricket balls are produced in aggregate by the firms in the market. Then q' 1000 1 14 1. q0 200 p' 30 1 12 2. p0 10 4 3. e= = 2. S 2 Summary When the supply curve is vertical, supply is completely insensitive to price and the elasticity of supply is zero. In other cases, when supply curve is positively sloped, with a rise in price, supply rises and hence, the elasticity of supply is positive. Like the price elasticity of demand, the price elasticity of supply is also independent of units. 4.7.1 The Geometric Method Consider the Figure 4.11. Panel (a) shows a straight line supply curve. S is a point on the supply curve. It cuts the price-axis at its positive range and as we extend the straight line, it cuts the quantity-axis at M which is at its negative range. The price elasticity of this supply curve at the point S is given by the ratio, Mq0/Oq0. For any point S on such a supply curve, we see that Mq0 > Oq0. The elasticity at any point on such a supply curve, therefore, will be greater than 1. In panel (c) we consider a straight line supply curve and S is a point on it. It cuts the quantity-axis at M which is at its positive range. Again the price elasticity of this supply curve at the point S is given by the ratio, Mq/Oq. Now, Mq< Oq 0000 and hence, eS < 1. S can be any point on the supply curve, and therefore at all points on such a supply curve eS < 1. Now we come to panel (b). Here the supply curve goes through the origin. One can imagine that the point M has coincided with the origin here, i.e., Mq0 has become equal to Oq0. The price elasticity of this supply curve at the point S is given by the ratio, Oq0/Oq0 which is equal to 1. At any point on a straight line, supply curve going through the origin price elasticity will be one. Price Elasticity Associated with Straight Line Supply Curves. In panel (a), price elasticity (eS ) at S is greater than 1. In panel (b), price elasticity (eS) at S is equal to 1. In panel (c), price elasticity (eS) at S is less than 1. • In a perfectly competitive market, firms are price-takers. • The total revenue of a firm is the market price of the good multiplied by the firm’s output of the good. • For a price-taking firm, average revenue is equal to market price. • For a price-taking firm, marginal revenue is equal to market price. • The demand curve that a firm faces in a perfectly competitive market is perfectly elastic; it is a horizontal straight line at the market price. • The profit of a firm is the difference between total revenue earned and total cost incurred. 65 • If there is a positive level of output at which a firm’s profit is maximised in the short run, three conditions must hold at that output level (i) p = SMC (ii) SMC is non-decreasing (iii) p ≥ AV C. • If there is a positive level of output at which a firm’s profit is maximised in the long run, three conditions must hold at that output level (i) p = LRMC (ii) LRMC is non-decreasing (iii) p ≥ LRAC. • The short run supply curve of a firm is the rising part of the SMC curve from and above minimum AVC together with 0 output for all prices less than the minimum AVC. • The long run supply curve of a firm is the rising part of the LRMC curve from and above minimum LRAC together with 0 output for all prices less than the minimum LRAC. • Technological progress is expected to shift the supply curve of a firm to the right. • An increase (decrease) in input prices is expected to shift the supply curve of a firm to the left (right). • The imposition of a unit tax shifts the supply curve of a firm to the left. • The market supply curve is obtained by the horizontal summation of the supply curves of individual firms. • The price elasticity of supply of a good is the percentage change in quantity supplied due to one per cent change in the market price of the good. Perfect competition Revenue, Profit Profit maximisation Firms supply curve Market supply curve Price elasticity of supply 66 Introductory Microeconomics 1. What are the characteristics of a perfectly competitive market? 2. How are the total revenue of a firm, market price, and the quantity sold by the firm related to each other? 3. What is the ‘price line’? 4. Why is the total revenue curve of a price-taking firm an upward-sloping straight line? Why does the curve pass through the origin? 5. What is the relation between market price and average revenue of a price-taking firm? 6. What is the relation between market price and marginal revenue of a price-taking firm? 7. What conditions must hold if a profit-maximising firm produces positive output in a competitive market? 8. Can there be a positive level of output that a profit-maximising firm produces in a competitive market at which market price is not equal to marginal cost? Give an explanation. Exercises 9. Will a profit-maximising firm in a competitive market ever produce a positive level of output in the range where the marginal cost is falling? Give an explanation. 10. Will a profit-maximising firm in a competitive market produce a positive level of output in the short run if the market price is less than the minimum of AVC? Give an explanation. 11. Will a profit-maximising firm in a competitive market produce a positive level of output in the long run if the market price is less than the minimum of AC? Give an explanation. 12. What is the supply curve of a firm in the short run? 13. What is the supply curve of a firm in the long run? 14. How does technological progress affect the supply curve of a firm? 15. How does the imposition of a unit tax affect the supply curve of a firm? 16. How does an increase in the price of an input affect the supply curve of a firm? 17. How does an increase in the number of firms in a market affect the market supply curve? 18. What does the price elasticity of supply mean? How do we measure it? 19. Compute the total revenue, marginal revenue and average revenue schedules in the following table. Market price of each unit of the good is Rs 10. 20. The following table shows the total revenue and total cost schedules of a competitive firm. Calculate the profit at each output level. Determine also the market price of the good. 21. The following table shows the total cost schedule of a competitive firm. It is given that the price of the good is Rs 10. Calculate the profit at each output level. Find the profit maximising level of output. Quantity Sold TR MR AR 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Quantity Sold TR (Rs) TC (Rs) Profit 0 0 5 1 5 7 2 10 10 3 15 12 4 20 15 5 25 23 6 30 33 7 35 40 Price (Rs) TC (Rs) 0 5 1 15 2 22 3 27 4 31 5 38 6 49 7 63 8 81 9 101 10 123 67 22. Consider a market with two firms. The following table shows the supply schedules of the two firms: the SS1 column gives the supply schedule of firm 1 and the SS2 column gives the supply schedule of firm 2. Compute the market supply schedule. 23. Consider a market with two firms. In the following table, columns labelled as SS1 and SS2 give the supply schedules of firm 1 and firm 2 respectively. Compute the market supply schedule. 24. There are three identical firms in a market. The following table shows the supply schedule of firm 1. Compute the market supply schedule. Price (Rs) SS1 (units) SS2 (units) 0 0 0 1 0 0 2 0 0 3 1 1 4 2 2 5 3 3 6 4 4 Price (Rs) SS1 (kg) SS2 (kg) 0 0 0 1 0 0 2 0 0 3 1 0 4 2 0.5 5 3 1 6 4 1.5 7 5 2 8 6 2.5 68 Price (Rs) SS1 (units) 0 0 1 0 2 2 3 4 4 6 5 8 6 10 7 12 8 14 25. A firm earns a revenue of Rs 50 when the market price of a good is Rs 10. The market price increases to Rs 15 and the firm now earns a revenue of Rs 150. What is the price elasticity of the firm’s supply curve? 26. The market price of a good changes from Rs 5 to Rs 20. As a result, the quantity supplied by a firm increases by 15 units. The price elasticity of the firm’s supply curve is 0.5. Find the initial and final output levels of the firm. 27. At the market price of Rs 10, a firm supplies 4 units of output. The market price increases to Rs 30. The price elasticity of the firm’s supply is 1.25. What quantity will the firm supply at the new price?